Betsy Hodges uttered one of my favorite lines during last month’s Transportation Mayoral Forum. We’d gotten to the wonky part of the discussion, about parking policy and zoning requirements. Hodges was one of the few candidates that really understood the parking question:
“I’m in my second term on the city council and in my first term especially I would always get this question, ‘what was the most surprising thing to you about being on city council?’ It took me a while to realize that the genuine answer to that question was the amount of time I spent talking about parking. Everything we do, parking gets talked about…”
Hodges is absolutely right. If you ask any politician, public works employee, or planner about parking they will immediately sigh. Their eyes will glaze over. They’ll stare off into the distance, and you’ll be lucky if you get another sensible word out of them for the rest of the day.

“You can’t pull in front first!”
I’ve written about this before, about how parking our cars somehow taps into some sort of lizard brain that turns us all into George Costanzas. When parking our cars, for some reason we believe that parking is a god-given right. While parking, we display neolithic competitive instincts, and cling to an irrational belief that parking should always be free AND convenient. Our parking lizard-brain leads us into all kinds of paradoxical dead end alleys. We end up driving around forever looking for a free parking spot, or leaving our car in an inconvenient place because we don’t want to move it.
(For today’s example of lizard-brain parking fiascos, see here.)
On a more macro-scale, it means that most of our buildings come with massive private parking lots designed for peak capacity (e.g. the day after Thanksgiving) that sit unused 99.9% of the time. It means requiring student apartment buildings to have expensive off-street parking garages that car-less students don’t even want. It means pitchfork uprisings in Lowertown, even though half of downtown Saint Paul is already being used for car storage. It means attempts on University Avenue to save 900 on-street parking spaces, when 20,000 off-street spaces sit empty most days mere feet away. (Caveat: The issue of on-street parking on University is a bit more complex than this, including safety and sidewalk concerns. But there’s no shortage of parking in general along University Avenue…)
Integrated Parking Management
Well, yesterday at the Saint Paul Transportation Committee I heard the first sensible discussion of parking policy in my Twin Cities’ memory, a presentation by Craig Blakley from the Saint Paul Planning and Economic Development office about the need for Integrated Parking Management.
Referring frequently to the “Cupcake debacle” (a now infamous bit of St Paul lore where a successful cupcake entrepreneur attempted in vain to open a new store on Grand Avenue, but — despite the mayor’s help — couldn’t get permitted because he didn’t have enough off-street parking spaces, and ended up moving to the Mall of America instead), Blakley spoke about the paradox of overbuilt parking, and the need to coordinate parking supply between businesses in an entire area, instead of on a one-by-one basis.
The gold standard of this approach is the city-run parking lot by the Grand Avenue Dunn Brothers. There, the city operates a collective parking lot on a church property, and assesses all the businesses in the area for it. That’s the model that the city is attempting to follow along University Avenue, and in other parts of the city. The issue has become urgent at the corner of Selby and Snelling, where a re-development is removing what had been a free public parking lot owned by a (since merged) bank. (Note: I’ve used this parking lot many times myself.)
Blakley has been trying to persuade the businesses in the area to agree to parking assessment district similar to the Grand Avenue situation, but with little luck so far. Businesses are reluctant to pay for a service (communal parking lot) that they’d recently been getting for free, and building and maintaining a parking lot is quite expensive.
What About the Market?
Despite the common sense being displayed in the city’s attempts at pooling parking supply, Saint Paul seems to be neglecting the key part of the picture. In my Streets.mn piece on parking policy from a few months ago, I summed up the situation like this:
It’s not just Lowertown. There are a dozen places where you could apply these principles. Right now, all over the Twin Cities people are pulling their hair out about parking in Uptown, Dinkytown, Selby Avenue, Grand Avenue, and pretty much anywhere else.
As long as we keep on-street parking free or absurdly cheap, almost everyone is going to be pissed off about it. That problem will never disappear, no matter how much paradise you pave. But if you get the prices right, parking problems will melt away.
Costanzas of the world won’t like it, but the key to solving the parking picture is to make sure that the price signals are correct. And so far, Saint Paul’s approach seems not to be focusing on price or demand. It’s only affecting supply, by consolidating and re-designing parking lots. If we want real change, we need to go the extra step and begin tweaking actual driver behavior.
There are a number of benefits to reforming parking prices in both downtowns, and at key dense nodes (Uptown, Snelby, Grand Avenue, etc.):
1) Market prices mean convenience for customers.
Right now, as everyone knows, in some places parking is a real pain in the ass. You have to drive around searching for spots, hoping to find one that’s free or extremely cheap. For many people, entering an expensive garage is admitting defeat.
Reforming prices by charging market rates for coveted on-street spots will mean that these spots will turn over more often, and go to those who really want/need them. By making these spots expensive, you’d ensure that one or more of them is open and available at all times. You’re basically trading convenience (it’s easy to find a spot) for money (a dollar more per hour).
2) Revenues can go directly to neighborhoods.
If you have increased parking meter revenue, it can begin to off-set the costs of key improvements. This is called a “Parking Benefit District” and for business owners, it’s basically free money. (You’re beginning to charge for a valuable service that had been provided for free.) This revenue stream, which at a corner like Selby and Snelling might exceed hundreds of thousands of dollars per year, could fund sidewalk improvements, flowers, streetscapes, or even defray the cost of a “free” collective parking lot a block or two away. The key is to give the purse-strings to the neighborhood. Let them decide how the money should be spent, NRP style.
3) Price signals fully use existing resources.

All the parking in downtown StP colored blue.
For a driver, a two-tiered parking structure would offer more choices. In a place like downtown Saint Paul, cheapskates could park in already-existing ramps for next to nothing while less mobile / Rockefellers pay a premium for a rock star spot on the street. Everyone benefits from more choices.
Parking policy reform would begin to make use of all the already-existing parking we’ve spent the last few decades building all through our downtowns. When bike lanes, new businesses, or infill developments are blocked because of parking riots, while existing ramps sit empty, that’s a real tragedy for a city.
The more I think about the political and material landscapes of our cities, the more I believe that parking policy is one of the few effective levers our cities have over transportation. If we want to really begin to change the calculus of transportation decisions, no amount of LRT lines, bike share kiosks, or education campaigns is going to change behavior as long as we keep offering free parking at every destination. To truly begin to shift away from the hegemony of single-occupancy vehicles, we need to change the parking equation. Parking Benefit Districts are the way forward.
Only tangentially related, but where are these cheap ramps? If I’m driving into downtown St Paul, it’s probably a weekend, and there is probably almost no one else around. Ramps are nearly empty. Streets are nearly empty. Yet ramp prices are the same as during the week (or I don’t know where the cheap ones are) and street meters are being actively enforced.
Heck, one summer weekend morning there were two cars parked on St. Peter Street, mine and one across the street, with the rest of the street parking open. I’d been a little over my meter time just walking around downtown for exercise. I’m thinking, “there is no demand at all for these parking places, they can’t possible by out giving tickets.”
Nope, I get back to my car and there is parking enforcement ticketing the other car. Someone had done downtown St Paul the favor of visiting it at as off-peak time as possible, when the city was almost entirely deserted, and was rewarded with a parking ticket. I made it back barely in time to avoid one for myself.
That’s almost as insane as building parking for peak capacity and failing to charge market prices for it. Maybe even more insane. As much as prices should go up to match demand, they should go down too, so as to actually welcome people into the city when no one is there.
Your comment about ramps is exactly my point. You make street more expensive, ramps less expensive until you balance out the supply and demand. It’s pretty basic economics.
I agree about your second point, too. I’d like to see parking rates fluctuate based on the time of day/year. There’s no reason to have meters go off in St Paul at 4:30 every night as a matter of principle…
(PS I don’t actually have a car, so don’t have much advice for you.)
Awesome post. I only wish that more people in governmental roles understood something as inane as parking this well. Reforming it would be strangely transformative.
Would it be prohibitively expensive to install systems analagous to the SFpark (http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/SFpark) system in key dense nodes?
I wish we could have the modest parking revolution you describe, however, I imagine we are more likely to see a drawn out evolution because politicians are afraid to upset the car loving populace. Parking meters prices will incrementally continue to increase, until businesses start losing customers and ultimately acquiesce to contributing to a shared parking structure. Of course having great public transit connecting dense areas would decrease demand for such shockingly extensive parking infrastructure. (your figure of downtown St. Paul was insane!) This might induce parking lot owners to sell to developers. I am not sure at what point these two seemingly conflicting forces even out. I am also hopeful that Car2go will induce more people to drop the extra car and that will further decrease parking demand. (now they just have to move to St. Paul) Now that I wrote this, I realize that without the coordinated policy you describe and elimination of minimum parking requirements, I will not live to see this transformation.
sigh
Bill – Just a note: The map with the highlighted Blue Parking lots in Downtown, that does NOT include underground parking structures below large buildings. So, basically there is MORE parking than what is being indicated on the map.
sigh.
I wonder what would happen if cities began charging property owners adequately for stroad frontage, perhaps as a component of property tax.
Aside from the obvious folly of a city selling an asset to pay its bills today, has Chicago selling its rights to parking meters resulted in higher prices/ changing parking costs in garages etc? Just curious.
Also sigh lol.
Hasta la victoria del aparcamiento siempre.